Article of the Month -
March 2012
|
Informal Development in Greece: New Legislation for Formalization, the
Chances for Legalization and the Dead Capital
Chryssy POTSIOU and Ifigenie BOULAKA, Greece
1) FIG-Vice President Chryssy
Potsiou is beside other responsibilities leading the new Task
Force (TF) on “Property and Housing” which is very relevant
in these turbulent times. The TF will have two special sessions during
the Working Week in Rome, May 2012. In this peer-reviewed paper the
authors present the results of a recent scientific research on the
problem of informal development in Greece and explain the new
legislation for formalization of those informal constructions, that are
built on legally owned land in the planned and the non-planned areas;
the existing informalities refer only to planning and building
regulations.
Key words: Informal Settlements, Dead Capital, Property
Taxation, Valuation, Legalization Tools, Property Formalization
SUMMARY
This paper presents the new findings of a focused research made by
the authors at the National Technical University of Athens on the
problem of informal development in Greece, on the newly adopted legal
tools used for formalization and on the existing loss of revenue due to
the informal construction in the non-planned areas. More specifically,
this paper presents the new legislation for formalization of those
informal constructions, that are build on legally owned land in the
planned and the non-planned areas; the existing informalities refer only
to planning and building regulations. The legislation was adopted by the
Greek Parliament, in 2010 and 2011. The legislation for the
formalization project, the first statistics and the reactions of those
involved is briefly described, analyzed and criticized. In addition,
this paper presents the first results of a study focused on the rough
estimation of the economic impact of the informal development in Greece;
starting with the estimation of the capital that is locked in the
informal constructions in the non-planned areas that by existing
legislation is not taxed, and cannot be legally transferred, inherited,
rented and mortgaged, which according to Hernando de Soto’s theory is
considered to be a “dead capital”.
The methodology followed for this research includes literature
research of previous publications on informal development in Greece and
existing and new legislation; interviews with property owners of
informal constructions and the local authorities in the various
municipalities and informal communities in Attika, the greater region of
Athens, the local real estate agents, the local constructors involved in
informal and/or semi-legal construction, the Greek experts (civil
engineers, planners, surveyors, etc), and the potential buyers in the
new situation established by the newly applied formalization project;
and a case study for the estimation of the dead capital in an area with
informal development in Attika, on-site visits, field and office work.
First a brief investigation of the current situation of the informal
development in Greece is given; a summary of the recent government’s
activity in this field is made and the new legislation for formalization
of informal properties for a 30-year period is reviewed. Then, the dead
capital locked in informal development in a community in Keratea, a
suburb in the greater region of Athens, is thoroughly investigated and a
rough estimation of the total dead capital locked in informal
development is attempted. Some thoughts and proposals for future
improvements follow.
1. INFORMAL DEVELOPMENT IN GREECE
Much of the research on informal development in Greece compiled until
2009 is already wrapped up in the 2010 FIG/UN HABITAT/GLTN/TEE
publication on “Informal Development in Europe. Experiences from Albania
and Greece” (Potsiou, 2010; Augustinus & Potsiou, 2011). An up-dated
description of the state-of-the-art of informal development in Greece
and the legal actions taken until now follows below.
For several years Greece has been dealing with poverty, immigration,
inefficient land administration and planning, and has experienced
several “generations” of informal or unplanned development. Emphasis has
been given to providing education for land professionals and on raising
awareness at all levels about the importance of securing and protecting
public and state-owned land (Potsiou & Basiouka, 2010), safeguarding the
environment and cultural heritage and acceptance of a tax system on real
estate private property. Civil engineering standards are enforced in
construction due to the high risk of earthquakes. Due to a continuous
effort to provide social services to the poor (Potsiou & Dimopoulou,
2011) there are very few slums and the majority of buildings are safe
and strong, built on legally owned land.
The major cause of informal development in Greece is the inefficiency
of the planning system and the over regularization of land.
Informalities in Greece are mainly related to an excess of zoning,
planning and building regulations, or construction without permission,
and not to squatting or a lack of ownership rights (Potsiou &
Dimitriadi, 2008; Tsenkova et al, 2009). Informal development mainly
includes construction of 1-2 storey single family houses, build without
building permits, in unplanned areas (Potsiou & Ioannidis, 2006), or 1-2
room extensions beyond legal constructions. Approximately one fifth (or
more than 1,000,000) of the constructions are informal build in small
parcels without a building permit, not including those built with a
permit but with slight informalities, like building-up in semi-open
spaces, change of uses, extra rooms in excess of the building permit
(Dimopoulou & Zentelis, 2007).
As detailed planning process is too expensive and slow, basic
infrastructure such as fresh water, electricity, telecommunication and
roads, have been provided in many areas without a detailed city plan
because local authorities try to upgrade the neighbourhoods
periodically. Greek people resort to informal construction when there is
no other realistic and affordable choice available that satisfies their
needs. A 2009 opinion pole, commissioned by the Technical Chamber of
Greece for the purposes of the FIG/UN HABITAT/GLTN/TEE 2010 study on
Informal Development in Europe-Experiences from Albania and Greece,
shows that 40% of respondents have difficulties in paying their housing
loans. About 50% of Greeks polled consider informal development on their
legally owned land as the only solution to their housing needs. It
should be noticed here that these figures refer mainly to the situation
as it was before the current economic crisis in Greece, which had only
started in October 2009.
Planning principles in Greece are not keeping up with national and
international social and economic changes. The existing spatial and
urban planning legislation is comprehensive but very complex (over
25,000 pages of legislation), focusing on the control of development and
protection of the environment and the public lands. This is not easily
interpreted either by professionals, or by citizens. Urban planning is
centralised and expensive. Detailed city planning studies at an average
take more than 15 years and cost higher than 6,000 € per hectare. In an
effort to facilitate market demand for housing, construction was allowed
in the non-planned areas, but obtaining building permits requires
involvement of more than 25 land related agencies, may take several
years, and in many cases requires court decisions (Potsiou & Dimitriadi,
2008). The planning process runs at a different speed to market needs
and cannot accommodate short term needs when there are large demands.
Planning criteria usually do not include local market interests. Certain
parameters make planning a complicated, expensive and time-consuming
task, such as the lack of necessary spatial data infrastructure (e.g.
cadastral maps, forest maps) and the fact that the areas under planning
already include formal or informal developments. Planned towns are
constrained and have limited space for further development. For that
reason real estate values are extremely high for condominiums in the
planned areas (even within blue collar areas) while salaries remain low.
The Greek Constitution gives priority to environmental and social
issues, rather than economic development needs (Potsiou & Basiouka,
2010). More than 50% of the country is protected land without any
compensation, ignoring the existing legal private property rights and
the damage such regulations cause to the private properties. However,
the state cannot respond well with its resources for management. This
policy restricts serious investment and impacts the economic development
of the country. The statutory environmental constraints are not clearly
defined and not delineated on maps. There are current nation-wide
projects to compile cadastral maps, forests and forest lands maps and
define the public coastal zone. These are expected to uncover long
existing problems in private properties and provide the tools for sound
decisions about major necessary reforms. Upon completion of such maps,
the state may claim property rights on “protected” areas, although
private interests have claimed registered ownership for several years.
Already, the first statistical data derived from the cadastral surveys
show that approximately 45% of the properties in the unplanned areas
recorded in the system is claimed by the state. Existing environmental
legislation creates a huge overlap between private and state rights, as
the state claims ownership over whatever parcel is characterized as
forest. This is a major reason for delays on urbanization projects.
By Constitution, informal construction cannot be legalized in Greece
if built in non-planned but protected areas (e.g. forest lands, coastal
zones, archaeological sites), or if it violates existing planning or
building regulations in the planned areas. Individual informal
constructions in highly protected areas that create serious damage are
demolished after court decisions. Strong laws and high penalties for
environmental protection are applied. This has significantly reduced the
environmental impact of informal development, especially in the coastal
zones, archaeological sites and forests of today. However, there are
still informal settlements with weak, disputed ownership rights within
areas that are forests and many in areas that are not forests today but
used to be forests some many decades ago; unfortunately there are no
statistics on that.
Few forest maps in the Attika region (where the problem seams to be
more significant) are already published and citizens are asked to submit
their objections in case their legally owned parcel is characterized as
“forest”; in such cases, according to the law the parts of the forest
maps that will not be disputed by citizens will be ratified as forest
areas meaning that according to existing legislation the state will then
become the land-owner of these areas. However, citizens are asked to pay
high fees in order to submit objections; unfortunately many Greek
politicians have mislead the Greek citizens by assuring them that there
is no need to spend money and submit objections on the published forest
maps assuring them that these maps will never be ratified.
All penalties derived from informal development are deposited to the
Special Fund for Implementation of Zoning and Urban Plans. This fund is
under the authority of the relevant Minister for the Environment, Energy
and Climate Change to decide how these funds will be used. That way the
revenue generated by penalties, which is considerable, is frequently
channelled directly to central government and not to local government.
This creates public mistrust. There would be more incentive for local
government agencies to resolve informal developments through new urban
plans if they benefited financially.
The only possibility for legalization of informal settlements in the
non-planned areas is through an enforcement of a city plan, if permitted
by the Constitution, improvement of infrastructure, and individual
inspection regarding safety controls. During the last decade hardly any
new plans were ratified though. Until legalization, such informal
constructions cannot be mortgaged, inherited, sold or rented formally,
even though owners have legal rights on the land parcels and they pay
property taxes.
2. THE ODYSSEY OF FORMALIZATION
This chapter investigates and comments on the new legal framework
adopted since 2009, that aims to “formalize planning informalities and
exceeds of building permits in the planned and non-planned areas for a
certain period of time”. The interviews made for this research are also
investigated here and have shown that unfortunately all people that have
been interviewed believe that until today there is no clear will and
concrete strategy or any published action plan on how the Greek
politicians will solve the informal settlement problems that have
accumulated and surface during the compilation of the Hellenic Cadastre
project and the forest maps threatening the success and sustainability
of these projects. Instead, only ad hoc legislation is adopted according
to the short-term specific political preferences each time and/or under
the pressure of the current economic crisis and the need to collect
money. Some examples, together with the results of the interviews with
(a) owners or occupants of informal constructions, (b) local
authorities, (c) involved experts, (d) local professionals like
constructors and estate agents and (e) interested buyers are
investigated and presented below.
2.1 New Legislation for formalization of planning and building
informalities
In 2008 the government started investigating procedures to legalize
planning and building violations that exist in the planned areas (like
the build-up on semi-open areas of the buildings). In September 2009 a
new law was adopted to serve this purpose which however aimed to
legalize only the informalities that exist within the ratified legal
outline of the volume of the building (Figure 1 right). This means that
any exceeds in the height of the building (Figure 1 left) or
constructions that exceed the legal horizontal coverage could not be
legalized by this law. By this law, legalization act was considered to
be permanent and was supposed to end up with a new property title in
which the correct area size of the property would be written. By
tradition, the political opposition claimed that this law is against the
Greek Constitution, as by legalizing the extra built-up area there would
be an increase of the area/floor ratio and thus an increase of the urban
density of the city and according to the existing Greek case law any
increase of urban density is supposed to have a negative impact on the
environment and is not permitted according to the Greek Constitution.
Figure 1. Illegal room under the roof of the building (left);
build-up semi-open areas within the ratified outline of the volume of
the building (right). Source: (Dimopoulou et al, 2007)
However, this old fashioned approach in Greece is against the current
global strategies for the adaptation and mitigation measures for climate
change and environmental protection, which mainly encourage an increase
of urban densities; e.g., “we need to take immediate actions to make
our cities more sustainable by revising our land-use plans, our
transport modalities, and our building designs… to reduce traffic
congestion, improve air and water quality, and reduce our ecological
footprint. In that respect urban density is a key factor … because less
energy is needed to heat, light, cool and fuel buildings in a compact
city where most of the population commutes by public transit” (El
Sioufi, 2010).
In October 2009 after the national elections, simultaneously with the
beginning of the economic crisis in Greece, Law 3843/2010 was prepared
by the new government and adopted by the Greek parliament with the
purpose to formalize only for a period of 40 years (not legalize), the
violations that exist within the ratified outline of the volume of the
building (Figure 1 right). By Law 3843/2010 the “Special Fund for
Implementation of Zoning and Urban Plans” was renamed into “Green Fund”
and the revenue of this fund was planned to be used for environmental
and regeneration projects.
During 2010 and until September 2011 declaration submission of the
above informalities was in fact optional and practically meaningless for
the owners, as transactions and mortgages of properties in the planned
areas with such minor informalities have been always permitted as there
was no specific relevant legal binding instrument in place.
Figure 2. Informalities in the planned areas that do not exist
within the ratified outline of the volume of the building, but can be
formalized by Law 4014/2011
In September 2011, under the pressure of the economic crisis, Law
4014/2011 was adopted by the Greek parliament. The Law was supported by
the majority of the members of the parliament of the two largest
political parties. By this law, in an effort to make the submission of
declaration of informalities within the planned areas obligatory
government has decided that for any future property transaction (formal
or informal) a declaration of the owner and a recent certificate signed
by a private engineer after a recent on site inspection is required
certifying that there is no informality in the real estate at the time
of transaction (before any transaction the property owner must hire a
private engineer to check the real situation of the construction with
the permit in case of informalities and certify compliance. This on-site
control must be done each the real property is transferred).
This measure is well accepted by the engineers however it means that
transaction costs for any property are increased significantly
regardless whether the property is legal or not, as the certificate is
necessary anyway before any transaction, and generally the transaction
procedure is becoming even more bureaucratic. This is against the global
strategies for the economy and the real estate markets that require a
reduction of the required time and costs for the property transactions
(World Bank, 2011). Recently, the relevant Minister has clarified that
this certificate is not required in case of mortgages.
Law 4014/2011 also allows the formalization of planning and building
informalities, only for a period of 30 years, of constructions which
exist either within the planned areas (but are not within the volume of
the building (Figure 1 left, Figure 2) or within the non-planned areas
and lie on legally owned parcels (Figure 3) that are not within the
“protected areas”. Within the 30 year period that those properties will
be formalized in the non-planned areas, local authorities are expected
to proceed with the compilation and implementation of the necessary city
plans, otherwise owners of such properties will be asked to pay
extremely high penalties in order to “buy” the necessary land and
formalize again. For the region of Attika, for example, in order to
build legally in the non-planned areas one needs a parcel of area size
at least 2 ha, while the average parcel where such informal properties
are build is 300-500 m2.
According to this law, for the next 30 years owners of these
properties will not be asked to pay any additional formalization
penalties for the illegalities that will declare now; connections with
utilities will be provided (to those few that are still denied); and
transactions will be permitted when the owner will pay all legalization
fees in advance and receive the relevant certificate of formalization.
Formalization fees are high but scalable depending on the year of
construction, the zone value, and whether the property serves as first
residence or not, and can be paid in instalments within the next 2.5
years. However, owners must hire engineers for the preparation of the
necessary plans and documents (surveyors should prepare high accuracy
surveying plans and civil engineers should inspect the construction’s
stability and submit a standardized form).
Figure 3. Informal settlements in the non-planned areas in
Keratea, Greece
Due to the crisis, by a revision of the draft law, 95% of the revenue
of the “Green Fund” (such as the revenue derived from the formalization
fees of build-up on semi-open areas, the informal buildings, the trade
of emission rights and the environmental penalties) will be directed to
the regular national budget.
Within the next 30 years if the municipalities will prepare detailed
city plans these informal settlements will be finally legalized. The
unfortunate situation in Greece is that this new legislation is not
accompanied with a reform of the planning system and procedures. Thus,
both Law 3843/2010 and Law 4014/2011 have inherited the weaknesses of
the Greek planning system (in terms e.g., complexity, confusion,
bureaucracy) and instead of solving the problem in the informal areas
new costs, mistrust and bureaucracy are added, the problem is simply
postponed for 30 years with an uncertain future.
In addition formalization procedure is insecure, costly and long and
with the current economic situation the success of this formalization
project is questionable.
2.2. First statistics, public opinion and concerns
Investigation of the first statistics and the opinions of those
involved in the project is of significant interest. There are
approximately 1.5 million small informalities in total within the
planned areas; until recently only 655,000 declarations have been
submitted for formalization according to Law 3843/2010. According to the
Ministry, most declarations have been submitted in Athens, Eastern
Attika, Thessaloniki, Creta, Evia, islands of Dodecanese, and Cyclades.
The formalization fees for this project are estimated to be 5-11% of the
tax value. The revenue until today is approximately 190 million €, while
the originally expected revenue from formalization of the build-up on
semi-open areas of the buildings was 800 million €.
Interviewed owners of properties that belong to the above category
feel that they are forced to pay large amounts of money for
formalization fees on top of all the other taxes the government enforces
on real properties; they are willing to participate but unable to pay;
the situation becomes absolutely unrealistic especially when existing
housing loans, all new taxes and formalization fees must be paid
simultaneously, within the same year.
The government extended the deadline for declaration submissions for
one more month hoping to collect more declarations and formalization
fees.
Formalization by Law 4014/2011 has started in September 2011 and is
supposed to finish by the end of November 2011. This law refers to more
than one million buildings mainly located in the non-planned areas all
over Greece. However, by the end of October 2011 only 30,000
declarations have been submitted, which so far has brought revenue of
only 6 million €. Greek government had announced a very optimistic
estimation that this formalization project would bring about 600-700
million € revenue by the end of 2011. A rough analysis of the declared
informal buildings shows that the majority of those declared are
commercial constructions and a few expensive informal residences. This
proves that so far only the wealthy owners declare their informal
properties. However, the majority of the Greek owners of informal
buildings cannot afford to pay fees due to severe salary reductions,
increased prices, and increased income and property taxes. Many wonder
what will then happen to the middle and low income owners of such
informal houses who cannot afford to pay? What will happen to those
informal settlements that exist on land claimed by the state? What will
happen to the vulnerable groups, like some Roma (Potsiou et al, 2011),
and to some minority who do not even have formal legal rights on land?
This legislation does not have an inclusive character.
In addition, the governmental decision that directs 95% of the
revenue of the “Green Fund” to the regular national budget instead of
using this revenue to fund environmental improvements introduced a new
high risk to the formalization project. According to the Greek case law
this could be against the Greek Constitution and the whole project maybe
locked at the Greek courts. Owners are aware of that risk; they
understand that even if they declare the informality and even if they
pay the formalization fees they may still be unable to formalize the
property. It is obvious that even if everything goes well they will be
scared to invest and improve these properties for the next 30 years.
However, the responsible Minister of Environment, Energy and Climate
Change has tried to comfort people by ensuring them that “the Council
of the State (Highest Court) understands the priorities of the country”.
Interviews with local authorities in areas with informal development
gave positive results; local authorities have long been struggling to
upgrade the informal settlements and integrate them into the city plans;
however, it is unclear how they will manage to find the necessary funds
for the necessary future planning. Planning procedures need to be
revised and property taxation revenue should be directed to local
authorities to enable them to meet the needs.
Involved experts like engineers are supportive as this project
creates new jobs for them. Much of the responsibility for the
implementation of planning rules and regulations is now transferred to
the private engineers. Engineers are asked to make a visual quality
evaluation of the construction and to fill out and sign a standardized
form about the stability of the building. The educational centre of the
Technical Chamber of Greece has organized e-training courses to improve
the engineers’ professional capacity in this field and to emphasize the
importance of the professional ethics. The Ethic Code for engineers is
reminded to those involved in this project; as the Ethic Code now
replaces the state supervision and operates like a social contract
between the individual professionals, the professional unions, the
clients and the society the TCG is currently working on the Code’s
revision. Engineers are asked to avoid unethical or unfair competition;
they are reminded that any abuse of a dominant position is prohibited;
they must inform the owners in a simple and understandable language; and
they should also publish and share their knowledge and experience in
order to improve the general capacity of the professional body.
Other local professionals like constructors and real estate agents
have been interviewed, too. Most of the local constructors have been
informally acting as real estate agents as well; the majority of them
are against the formalization law; they are anxious to sell the
semi-legal constructions they have under construction as fast as
possible fearing a price decrease. As construction is long restricted in
the non-planned areas and informal houses can not be legally
transferred, so far the semi-legal constructions they manage to build
are not too many and they are very expensive and profitable. Probably,
through formalization a great number of properties are expected to be
available in the formal market, which will increase the supply and the
prices are expected to fall.
In general real estate market is heavily affected by the economic
crisis in Greece. Local real estate agents informed that the market in
informal areas is practically frozen since 30 years ago and in cases
there was a sporadic transaction owners were in need and were always
prepared to sell less than half of the “real value”. With Greeks facing
the economic crisis today only foreigners may be possible buyers in the
Greek real estate market; this is happening in the areas close to the
sea.
Finally, it was interesting to hear the view of some foreigners,
potential buyers interested in buying single houses in the suburban
coastal areas in Greece. In such areas a number of informal vacation
houses exist, which by the formalization will be available for sale. The
high formalization fees and the 30 years formalization duration is
considered to be a great weakness though.
Their views can be summarized in the following statement made by a
well informed foreigner for the purposes of this research: “The sale
of "protection" services has a long history in the major cities in the
United States. A store or restaurant owner is approached by the
neighbourhood boss of thugs and advised that without his protection the
security of the enterprise cannot be guaranteed. Doubt on the part of
the store-owner is dissuaded when his windows are blown out the next
day. Protection will cost the proprietor a percentage of his gross (not
net) income. It is extortion in its simplest form. Accordingly, I was
astonished to read of the proposal of the Greek government to charge
certain homeowners a fee (tax? penalty?) for protection against the
demolishment of their houses for the next 30 years. It is extortion of a
higher order.
The condition of "informal development", i.e., the construction of
buildings without building permits, or construction in otherwise banned
areas such as a forest or coastal zone, is a recognized problem in
Greece, the Balkans, Eastern Europe and in fact everywhere, in virtually
every country (including Western Europe or U.S ). People circumvent
bureaucracy and inconvenient public policy by taking the issue into
their own hands to create their own housing. Much of this construction
is of good quality, acceptable as to sanitation and safety requirements.
It is also unrecorded in the local cadaster and is off the property tax
rolls, cannot be mortgaged and carries the threat of public prosecution.
The UN and the EU, as well as other organizations continue to study the
problem; solutions include everything from demolishment of substandard
or environmentally inappropriate construction to penalties and fees for
final recognition and legalization. The Greek proposal is an example of
this latter approach - except that what is offered to the homeowner, at
significant cost, is protection for only a limited period. Telling a
family that their home is safe for now, but may be reconsidered for
demolishment 30 years hence - or for a new round of fees - is clear
extortion-by-government.”
3. ESTIMATION OF THE DEAD CAPITAL
In 2009, inspired by Hernando de Soto’s theory (de Soto, 2000) the
authors of this paper have initiated a research at the National
Technical University of Athens in order to estimate the “dead capital”
which is locked in the informal constructions in the non planned areas
in Greece, in an effort to emphasize the need for an inclusive
legalization project. The methodology followed includes a case study in
an area with informal development, on site inspections and field work,
interviews with local experts, professionals and local authorities and
office work.
A case study area named Ag. Marina - Mikrolimano, in the municipality
of Keratea was selected (Figure 3 left and Figure 4). The area of
interest is a typical informally developed area without detailed plans.
All parcels are legally owned but due to their small size it is not
possible to obtain building permit. However, also due to their small
size it s not possible to be used for farming. However, subdivision of
rural land was permitted in the past. As this area is close to the
capital city and by the seaside, in the General Urban Plan it is planned
to be a vacation area appropriate for second –vacation residences. As
the planning process is too slow the only pragmatic solution for land
owners is the informal housing. The total area size of this community is
170 ha and the registered permanent population is 142 inhabitants;
however in the summer time the population is up to 2000 inhabitants. The
area is mainly used for vacation purposes but gradually it becomes a
permanent-residence area. The majority of the buildings are informal
constructions.
Figure 4. Satellite image (WorldView 1) of the case study area of
2009 (left) and aerial photo of 1980 (right)
The area is still non-planned; however the municipality in 2006 has
managed to finish the necessary cadastral map in order to proceed with
the compilation of a detailed city plan.
The majority of informal settlements in Greece are similar
constructions with similar problems, in sub-urban and coastal areas
without detailed plans. Some of them are in areas where a General Urban
Plan is already ratified, some others not. If the General Urban Plan is
missing then this has to be finished first and the detailed plan
follows. This procedure may last more than 30 years.
The case of Keratea is a good sample area for this kind of research
and results derived from this research can be easily applied to the rest
of the cases. Unfortunately there are no general maps showing the areas
that are already covered by General Urban Plans and detailed city plans
in Greece. Some of the plans are in analog form, some other in digital
form all scattered in the various municipalities. Currently the
responsible Ministry is making an effort to collect all these plans and
overlap those with the recently compiled forest maps; this is a very
cumbersome task. It is roughly estimated that over 1,000,000 informal
constructions all over Greece belong to this category.
The local authority has provided the digital cadastral map in CAD
format (Figure 5 left) to facilitate this research. Additional data used
are airphotos of the area of 1980, a recent orthophoto derived from
KTIMATOLOGIO SA and a satellite image of 2009. The cadastral map was
edited in a GIS environment.
The total number of parcels in the area under study is 2,433; 62% of
them are not developed and 38% have a building. The total area size of
the parcels is 123.5 ha. Figure 5 (right) shows the percentage of
parcels according to their area size in m2. It is shown that 99% of the
parcels are less than 0.4 ha (the minimum required parcel size in order
to acquire a building permit); while 71% of the parcels are smaller than
500m2. This is a typical pattern in the greater Attika region.
The number of buildings in the study area is 1736. Of them 83.8% are
one-storey constructions, 15.6% two-storey and 0.6% three-storey. The
majority of the buildings are smaller than 200m2 (95.7%). The total
build up area size is 106,229m2.
A data base was created in order first to calculate the total
“non-taxed” tax value in the area under study. The data base was
structured according to the standardized procedure used by the tax
office for the calculation of the tax value of land in the non-planned
areas or for settlements where no specific building regulations exist.
It should be clarified here that according to existing legislation in
Greece only the developed rural parcels (those that have buildings) must
be taxed; other rural parcels are not supposed to be declared and taxed.
Figure 5. Left: Cadastral map with buffer zones according to the
distance from the sea.
Right: Distribution of buildings according to their size
3.1 Total tax value in the area under study
According to the tax office the tax value of land is the sum of the
following three parts:
a) the Basic Land Value (BLV), which is determined by
multiplying the area size of the parcel by the initial basic value
(IBV), and by the land-use coefficient. The initial basic value is the
tax value per m2 determined by the tax office, which depends on the
location, distance from the sea (with a scalable value) and access to a
specific national or regional road. The land-use coefficient depends on
the land-use category, e.g., agricultural land, trees or annual
cultivations, irrigated or not; pastures; rocks; forests; mines; and
other special commercial uses. The land-use coefficient value varies
from 1.0-1.8. In the study area the IBV varies as following:
- 15.50 € for a distance up to 100m from the sea
- 13.00 € for a distance between 100m -200m
- 13.00 € for a distance between 200m-500m
- 11.00 € for a distance between 500m -800m
- 6.00 € for a distance more than 800m
Zones (buffers) of a distance of 100, 200, 500 and 800 m from the sea
shore were created (Figure 5 left). All parcels in the study area are
considered to be not irrigated (according to regulations as they are
served by a network of drinking water), agricultural land with annual
cultivation; so the land-use coefficient is 1.0.
ΒLV = Parcel Area Size m2 x IBV x land-use coefficient (1)
b) the Plot Land Value (PLV), which is determined only if the
parcel is developed and only if the area size of the building is larger
than 15m2. The PLV is calculated by multiplying the initial plot value
(IPV) (determined by the tax office and depending on the location), by
the building area size, by the use of the building coefficient (UCB)
(which varies between 0.40 (for agricultural use) and 1.20 (for
commercial use) and for houses it gets the value 1.0), and by the
specific coefficients (SC). The specific coefficients are applied on the
following specific cases: for building older than 30 years (0.50), for
rough construction made of mud-bricks and/ or roof made by plates or
other cheap material (0.50), for buildings that are not connected to
electricity (0.90) or water utilities (0.95), for buildings half-damaged
by natural hazards (0.80).
In the case study area the IPV is 150.00€; all buildings in the study
area are connected with electricity and water utilities. Buildings older
than 30 years in the study area have been located by comparing the
airphotos of 1980 with the recent ones.
PLV = IPV x Building Area Size m2 x UCB x SC (2)
c) the Value of Further Development (VFD), which is determined
only for those parcels that can be further developed according to
existing zoning and planning regulations. In the study area anyway no
development is permitted as 99% of the buildings are constructed in
parcels smaller than 0,4ha, so VFD=0.
For the estimation of the tax value of each parcel the sum of the
above values may need to be multiplied by specific coefficients in the
following cases:
- Existence of “co-ownership” rights (coefficient value 0.9). Due
to lack of relevant data for this study it was considered that
owners of all parcels had “100% ownership” (there is no co-owner).
- Access to national, regional, rural or private road. This
coefficient varies from 1.3 up to 0.9. The existing road network in
the study area is a municipal network and in such case for all
parcels that have access to this network the relevant coefficient
gets the value 1.1 (except of some specific cases that are parcels
without access to a road; in such cases the relevant co-efficient
gets the value 0.9)
- Minimum distance of the parcel from the sea smaller than 800m.
This coefficient varies from 1.8 up to 1.0.
- If the parcel is under expropriation; this coefficient is 0.5.
No parcel in the study area belongs to this category.
Vtax land = (BLV + PLV+ VFD) x Specific coefficients (3)
According to the above analysis the calculated total tax value of all
individual land parcels in the study area is calculated: Vtax land = 44
million €
This asset should theoretically be taxed but as the constructions are
illegal, undeclared and invisible until today it is not.
3.2. The real “dead capital” locked in informal developments in
the non planned areas
In the following an attempt is made to estimate the dead capital that
is locked in the study area. According to information derived from the
local real estate agents the market value of the parcels in the greater
area is approximately 100 €/m2. So, the total market value of the land
under study is 123,500,000 €.
Construction costs for the illegal constructions are higher due to
the risk undertaken by the constructor (if arrested on site he will be
imprisoned). For example while the regular costs for the concrete parts
of the constructions is 240 €/m3, informal concrete construction costs
are double (480 €/m3). The cost is doubled due to corruption. However,
this is limited only to the concrete parts of the construction and not
to all other material costs. So, the total construction cost of an
informal building is estimated to be 1.5 times higher than the regular
costs. Through the field work the buildings in the area have been
classified into three categories according to their construction
quality. The total construction cost for each category is estimated as
following:
- Good quality: 1,100 €/m2
- Medium quality: 900 €/m2
- Bad quality: 700 €/m2
A classification of all the buildings in the area of interest
according to their construction time was attempted by interpretation of
aerial photos of various years. It is noticed that a classification of
all buildings in three categories according to their age shows that
there is much overlap with the classification according to the building
quality. An explanation could be that owners of informal buildings
hesitate to invest on construction improvements due to the risk of
demolition. Few exceptions were noticed. For the purposes of this
research it was then decided to merge these two classifications into one
(Table 1). So, buildings of good quality will have age co-efficient
0.80; buildings of medium quality 0.70; and buildings of bad quality
0.60. For this study informal constructions build before 1983 are not
demolished and can be transferred so they are not included in the
estimation of the total dead capital (however according to law 4014/2011
these building must be formalized, too).
An example of the estimation of the dead capital locked in the
individual property shown in Figure 6 is given below. The parcel size is
304.3 m2 and the build up area size (2-storey building) is 183.8 m2.
Figure 6. Informal building in the study area
It is considered that the “dead” capital is the potential market
value of the real estate if legalized. This is the sum of the market
value of land (according to the available market data in the greater
area) plus the construction costs (as there is no market data
available).
“Dead” Capital |
= Market value of land
+ Construction costs |
where: Market value of land |
= Parcel size x Value of land/m2 |
|
= 304.3 m2 x 100 €/m2
= 30,430 € |
Construction costs |
= Build up area size x
Construction cost/m2 x Coefficient of age |
|
= 183.8 m2 x 1,100
€/m2 x 0.80 (coefficient of age) = 202,180 €
|
So: “Dead” capital
|
= 232,610 €; the
amount of money the owner has invested in the property |
Real property tax
value |
= 49,608 €; estimated
according to the tax procedure. |
This procedure was followed in order to estimate the dead capital
locked in all individual buildings in the area under study. The estimate
of the total dead capital in the study area is given below.
On site inspections for the classification of the constructions in
the area under study have shown that:
Good quality buildings: |
25.1% of the total number of buildings |
Medium quality buildings: |
46.3% |
Bad quality buildings: |
28.6% |
The total cost of construction is 67,610 million € (Table 1). The
total market value of land of the developed parcels in the study area
is: 100€/m2x (123.5 ha x 0.38) = 40 million €
The “Dead” Capital for the study area is:
“Dead” Capital = Market value of land + Construction costs = 67,61 + 40
= 107,67 million €
Table 1. Estimate of the total market value of the constructions
in the study area
For the whole Greece, a rough estimation gives:
- The estimated “Dead” Capital for approximate 1 million informal
constructions in the non planned areas is ~ 72 billion €. This asset
is not mortgaged, not taxed and cannot be transferred until today.
- If government decides an increase of the tax values in such
areas so that the tax value will be ½ of the market value, the tax
value will be 36 billion €
- With a legalization fee ~7% of tax value (proposed by the
authors) the expected revenue could be up to ~2.5 billion €. To this
sum all other loss of revenue should be added due to loss of annual
property taxes, loss of transaction fees, loss of investment for
further environmental improvements (green real estate), loss of job
positions, etc.
4. CONCLUSIONS-PROPOSALS
The municipality of Keratea and all other municipalities all over the
country that cannot afford to provide detailed plans in their
neighborhoods according to market needs have a significant economic
impact as the real estate market is blocked. Greek citizens are expected
to pay high fees for a formalization project that has an unknown future.
Moreover expected results are questionable due to the current economic
crisis. The formalization project should be accompanied with a revision
of the planning procedures and zoning regulations and construction
permitting in Greece. Legalization should be coordinated with other
major projects, too, like the cadastre and the compilation of the forest
maps. Building permit requirements need to be simplified to prevent
duplication of surveying activities.
By this research authors wish to emphasize the need for an itegrated
strategy aiming to a clear and inclusive legalization of informal
development in Greece which requires a legal reform, too. Legalization
should be permanent and affordable to all. Attention should be paid to
eliminate the broader economic impacts of informal development, to
implement a more fair property taxation, and to acquiring the public
trust.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Special thanks to the municipality of Keratea and to KTIMATOLOGIO SA
for providing access to information, to IEKEM TEE for their cooperation
and information sharing on the relevant e-training courses and the
opinions of the Greek experts on the formalization project, to the Greek
owners of informal houses for their trust during the on-site visits,
field work and interviews, to the local real estate agents for their
valuable contribution to the estimate of the dead capital, and to the
foreigners who have kindly participated to the interviews and expressed
their concerns about the project.
REFERENCES
- Augustinus, C., Potsiou, C., 2011. Informal Urban Development in
Europe. In: Proceedings of the FIG Working Week 2011, Marrakech,
Morocco,
http://www.fig.net/pub/fig2011/ppt/ts07g/ts07g_augustinus_potsiou_5192_ppt.pdf
- De Soto, H, 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism
Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. Basic Books, 2000.
ISBN 0-465-01614-6.
- Dimopoulou, E., Zentelis, P., 2007. Informal settlements within
a spatial development framework. In: Proceedings of Joint FIG
Commission 3, UN/ECE Working Party on Land Administration and UN/ECE
Committee on Housing and Land Management Workshop, Sounio, Greece
(unpaginated CD-ROM).
- El Sioufi, M., 2010. Climate Change and Sustainable Cities:
Major Challenges Facing Cities and Urban Settlements in the Coming
Decades. In: Proceedings of the XXIV FIG International Conference
2010, Sydney, Australia,
http://www.fig.net/pub/fig2010/papers/ps03/ps03_elsioufi_4658.pdf
- Potsiou, C., 2010. Informal Urban Development in Europe.
Experiencies from Albania and Greece, Full Version, FIG, UN HABITAT,
GLTN, Technical Chamber of Greece, p.116.
- Potsiou, C., Basiouka, S., 2010. Land expropriation in Greece -
A case study for Road Networks. In: Proceedings of the Joint FIG
Commission 3 and Commission 7 Workshop, Sofia, Bulgaria.
- Potsiou, C., Dimitriadi, 2008. Tools for Legal Integration and
Regeneration of Informal Development in Greece: A Research Study in
the Municipality of Keratea. Surveying and Land Information Science
(SaLIS), vol. 68 (2), pp. 103-118.
- Potsiou, C., Dimopoulou, E., 2011. Access to Land and Legal
Rights on Land and Housing Aspects of Greek Roma. In: Proceedings of
the FIG Commission 3 Workshop 2011, Paris.
- Potsiou, C., Ioannidis, C., 2006. Informal settlements in
Greece: The mystery of missing information and the difficulty of
their integration into a legal framework. In: Proceedings of the 5th
FIG Regional Conference, Accra, Ghana,
http://www.fig.net/pub/accra/papers/ts03/ts03_04_potsiou_ioannidis.pdf
- Tsenkova, S., Potsiou, C., Badyina, A., 2009. Self-Made Cities.
United Nations Publications. ISBN 978-92-1-117005-4., p. 113.
- World Bank, 2011. Doing Business 2011 - Making a difference for
entrepreneurs. p. 267,
http://www.doingbusiness.org/~/media/FPDKM/Doing%20Business/Documents/Annual-Reports/English/DB11-FullReport.pdf
BIOGRAPHICAL NOTES
Chryssy POTSIOU
Dr Surveyor Engineer, Ass. Professor, School of Rural & Surveying
Engineering, National Technical University of Athens, in the field of
Cadastre and Spatial Information Management. FIG Commission 3 chair
(2007-2010). FIG Vice President (2011-2014). Elected bureau member of
the UN ECE Working Party for Land Administration (2001-2013), member of
the management board of KTIMATOLOGIO SA; elected bureau member of
HellasGIs and the Hellenic Photogrammetric and Remote Sensing Society.
Ifigenie BOULAKA
Surveying Engineer, graduated from National Technical University of
Athens in 2010, working in the private sector.
CONTACTS
Ass. Professor Dr Chryssy POTSIOU
School of Rural & Surveying Engineering, National Technical University
of Athens
9 Iroon Polytechniou St.
Athens
GREECE
Tel. +302107722688
Fax +302107722677
Email:
chryssy.potsiou@gmail.com
|