Article of the Month -
March 2006
|
Cadastre in Itself Won’t Solve the Problem: The Role of
Institutional Change and Psychological Motivations in Land Conflicts – Cases
from Africa
Dr. Babette WEHRMAN, Germany
This article in .pdf-format
1)
This article has been prepared for the 5th FIG Regional Conference -
Promoting Land Administration and Good Governance to be held in Accra,
Ghana, March 8-11, 2006. This paper was not presented in the conference.
Key words: land conflicts, land market, land administration,
institutions, psychological motivation, conflict resolution
1. INTRODUCTION
The governments of many African countries are currently investing in the
improvement of their land administration – aiming mainly to develop an
efficient land market. As a side product, there is the objective to decrease
land conflicts through the implementation of a functioning land registration
and/or cadastral system. Experience, however, shows that more is needed than
surveying, demarcation and land registration to avoid severe land conflicts.
The question therefore arises what are the deeper roots of land conflicts
and how can we respond to them.
2. SHORT-COMINGS OF THE LAND MARKET AND ITS INSTITUTIONS FACILITATING
LAND CONFLICTS
2.1 Economic efficient land markets can cause land conflicts
Not only imperfect land markets, even a perfect land market cannot
prevent land conflicts if it is not regulated by institutions. For the
purpose of this paper two types of institutions are distinguished:
constitutive and regulative institutions. Constitutive institutions are
needed to enable an economic efficient land market to work (such as land
rights, land registration and rule of law), while regulative institutions
are necessary to make the land market socially sustainable and
environmentally sound (such as land management and ethic principles).
However, even if all these institutions are in place, land conflicts can
still occur. This is mainly due to extreme emotional and material needs.
2.2 Institutions constituting and regulating the land market to
minimize land conflicts do not work properly in developing countries
In most African countries, many constitutive and regulative institutions
have massive functional deficits: Land rights are most often characterized
by a fragmented or overlapping legislation and legal pluralism, resulting in
unclear property rights and consequently land ownership conflicts. Land
administration authorities dealing with land registration, land information
systems, land use planning and land development lack trained staff,
technical infrastructure, and financial resources. Beyond that,
administrative services are over-centralised and responsibilities are often
not clearly assigned or overlap each other, thus impeding cooperation and
coordination. As a result, the little available and mostly incomplete or
isolated data on land ownership and land use is being gathered by different
non-cooperating institutions, making it difficult or even impossible to use
it properly. Endless procedures and low levels of implementation are the
result. Therefore, neither institutions constituting nor those regulating
the land market make a substantial contribution to avoiding land conflicts.
Given the low salaries and the openness to motivation payments of the people
working within these institutions they rather contribute to land conflicts.
Legal security is furthermore limited by insufficient implementation of
rule-of-law principles, while mechanisms for sustainable land development
suffer from the fact that ethical principles are not broadly acknowledged.
For all institutions, lacking implementation is the crucial point. Unclear
implementation guidelines and contradicting legislation worsen the
situation. Political will is very unsteady. Generally, it can be concluded
that imperfect constitutive institutions of land markets promote land
ownership conflicts, while poor regulative institutions are responsible for
land ownership as well as land use conflicts.
Fig. 1: Constitutive and regulative institutions
of the land market
Own draft
3. THE DEEPER CAUSES OF LAND CONFLICTS
3.1 Dysfunctional institutions only act as catalyst of land conflicts,
selfish individual interests being the deeper causes
It needs to be stressed that functional deficits are not the core reason
for land conflicts; they merely facilitate them. Profit maximisation of a
multitude of actors is the driving force, either by unjustly grabbing land
or by excluding disadvantaged sections of the population from legally using
land. Theoretically, these actors include all social gate keepers, mostly
identical with principals in principal-agent-relationships. Notoriously low
wages in the public sector contribute to corrupt behaviour of social
gatekeepers in this field. In my opinion, however, the decisive factor for
these irregularities is the “normality of misbehaviour”: Nepotism,
corruption, and disregard for regulations are considered normal by the
population. Social and religious values are of little relevance for everyday
life; self interest is paramount to public interest. This underlines the
importance of ethical values and rule-of-law principles in preventing land
conflicts. If individual profit maximisation – under widespread absence of
functioning institutions – is the underlying reason for land ownership
conflicts, then a capitalistic land market associated with increasing land
prices can be seen as facilitator. (For as long as land has no monetary
value, land ownership conflicts occur comparably seldom.) In this situation,
dysfunctional institutions constituting and regulating the land market act
merely as catalysts of land conflicts – especially in times of institutional
change.
3.2 Psychical fears and desires resulting in emotional and material
needs are at the root of land conflicts
As any egoistic behaviour, taking advantage of functional deficits for
the sake of reckless individual profit maximisation is based on emotional
and material needs, which again are a consequence of psychical fears and
desires. Therefore, psychical phenomena form the basis of land conflicts. A
typical psychical fear is the fear of existence. This fear can result in
extreme emotional and material needs such as the need for shelter, the
longing for survival and self-esteem – in some cases resulting in a desire
for power – and strong need for independence – often resulting in the
accumulation of wealth. It is mainly the combination of very strong
emotional and material needs (seeking power and wealth) that let people
either break rules (institutions) or profit from institutional shortcomings.
Land conflict resolution should therefore look at the psychical fears and
desires of those breaking the law or profiting from loopholes – especially
in those situations where illegal behaviour is rather the rule than the
exception. This is the case in many post-conflict countries where psychical
fears and desires and the thereby provoked emotional and material needs are
a common phenomena influencing the entire society and overall development.
4. INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AS CATALYST
Institutional changes are conflict prone and therefore tend to be phases
of increased land conflicts. While some forms of land conflicts can occur
under different and even stabile institutional frame conditions (such as
border or inheritance conflicts), others depend on the kind of institutional
change. Multiple sales due to legal pluralism for instance are typical for
slow institutional changes that lead to the overlapping of two systems,
while illegal sales of state land are quite common in situations of either
abrupt institutional change that are marked by a temporary absence of rules
(transformation) or longer term absence of a functioning legitimated
institutional frame (civil war, dictatorship).
5. INTERDEPENDENCY OF FACTORS CAUSING LAND CONFLICTS
Changing frame conditions often provide the base for land conflicts:
natural disasters such as droughts and floods leading to rural-urban
migration, natural population growth, the resulting increase in the demand
of land and consequently land prices, the introduction of the market economy
giving land a monetary value and thereby eradicating traditional ways of
land allocation, increasing poverty making it difficult to acquire land
legally and last but not least an institutional change causing a temporary
institutional vacuum at the land market create fears, desires, needs,
interests, attitudes and opportunities concerning land use and ownership
that are no longer controlled and therefore easily lead to land conflicts
(see Fig. 2).
Fig. 2: Interdependency of land conflict causes
Own draft
Poverty, institutional change and other changes in society (including war
and peace) influencing each other provoke strong psychological desires and
fears (such as fear of existence, desire to be loved) which result in
extreme emotional and material needs (such as the need for shelter, feelings
of revenge, the longing for survival and self-esteem – in some cases
resulting in a need for power – and strong need for independence – often
resulting in the accumulation of wealth). Given the institutional
shortcomings due to institutional change, these emotional and material needs
– sometimes supported by the sudden opportunities to reap economic profits –
result in either taking advantage of institutional weaknesses, ignoring
formal and/or informal institutions or in preventing their
(re-)establishment.
Looked at these causes from a different analytical perspective, they can
also be distinguished in political, economic, socio-economic,
socio-cultural, demographic, legal, administrative, technical (concerning
land management), ecological and psychical causes (see Fig. 3). All of these
causes are also included in the model presented in figure 2: Political,
economic, socio-economic, socio-cultural, demographic and ecological causes
are part of the changing framework. Legal, administrative and technical
causes are summarized under the institutional shortcomings. The psychical
causes have already been addressed (see 3.2).
Fig. 3: Causes of urban and peri-urban land
conflicts
Causes |
Examples |
Political causes |
- change of the political and economic system
- lack of political stability and continuity, lack of predictability
- introduction of (foreign, external) institutions that are not
accepted
- war/post-war situation
|
Economic causes |
- evolution of land markets
- increasing land prices
- limited capital market
|
Socio-economic
causes |
- poverty and poverty-related marginality/exclusion
- extreme unequal distribution of power and resources (incl. land)
- lacking micro-finance options for the poor
|
Socio-cultural
causes |
- destroyed or deteriorated traditional values and structures
- rejection of formal institutions (new, foreign, external)
- low level of education and lack of information on institutions and
mechanisms of land markets
- high potential for violence
- abuse of power
- strong mistrust
- helplessness of those disadvantaged
- unregistered land transactions
- fraud of administration and/or individuals
- patronage-system, clientelism
- strong hierarchical structure of society
- heterogeneous society, weak sense of community, lacking
identification with society as a whole
|
Demographic
causes |
- strong population growth and rural exodus
- new and returning refugees
|
Legal causes |
- legislative loopholes
- contradicting legislation
- legal pluralism
- traditional land law without written records or clearly defined
plot and village boundaries
- formal law which is not sufficiently disseminated and known
- limited claims of legal entitlement by disadvantaged
- insufficient establishment of rule-of-law-principles (e.g. lack of
independent courts)
- insufficient implementation of legislation
- missing or not applied mechanisms for sanctions
|
Administrative
causes |
- insufficient implementation of formal regulations
- centralism (e.g. centralised land use planning)
- corruption
- insufficient control over state land
- lack of communication, cooperation, and coordination within and
between different government agencies as well as between public and
private sector (if existent at all)
- lack of responsibility/accountability
- limited access (distance, illiteracy, costs etc.)
- insufficient information for the public
- limited/inexistent public participation, especially in land use
planning
- insufficient staff and technical/financial equipment of public
agencies
- very low wages in the public sector
- low qualification level of public employees
- missing code of conduct
- lack of transparency
|
Technical
causes |
- missing or inaccurate surveying
- missing land register (e.g. destroyed) or it does not meet modern
requirements
- missing, outdated or only sporadic land use planning or not
adapted to local conditions
- insufficient provision of construction land
- missing housing programs
|
Ecological causes |
- erosion/drought/floods leading to urban migration
- floods and storms in squatter settlements
|
Psychical causes |
- fear for one’s existence
- lack of self-esteem
- loss of identity
- collective suffering
- desire for revenge
- thirst for power
|
Source: Wehrmann 2005
6. EXAMPLES FROM DIFFERENT AFRICAN COUNTRIES
6.1 Accra, Ghana
The institutional change that occurred in Ghana which still has an impact
on the current situation started with the colonalization. The import of
colonial/European/British institutions that have been introduced by the
British and later be kept after independence by the now independent Republic
of Ghana resulted in legal pluralism that still characterizes today’s
situation. The slow transformation from one system to another has never
destroyed the entire institutional framework – although many formal as well
as informal institutions are ignored. While being weak, the institutional
setting functions to a certain degree.
Fig. 4: Constitutive and regulative institutions
of the land market in Accra
Wehrmann 2005
An analysis of the land market insitutions in Accra showed that the
weakest point is the implementation. The questions now is why are the formal
institutions not implemented sufficiently. Apart from limited financial
means and human capacities, lack of coordination and cooperation etc. a main
problem is the lack of acceptance of formal institutions. This might partly
be due to long procedures and high (official as well as inofficial) costs
but it also reflects people’s general perception of and attitude towards the
state. What’s the reason for it? The negligence of autochthonous
institutions and the attempt to replace them by external models (European
institutions) have in certain cases resulted in non-acceptance and
viola¬tions of government regulations by traditional authorities. Multiple
sales of land by different traditional chiefs (head of stools, head of
families) and the violation of land use regulations by individuals represent
the most common forms of land conflicts.
In spite of all the existing laws and the many institutions dealing with
land management and land administration, there have been more than 60.000
land cases in Accra at the beginning of the new millenium, keeping the
courts busy (Daily Graphic, 15.11.2001). The most common land conflicts
apart form boundary conflicts are multiple sales of land. These are
conflicts where several people – most often traditional authorities – claim
being the owner and sell the land to different innocent clients. Although
these activities are facilitated by the weaknesses of the land
administration, the question remains why some people exploit them while
others don’t.
The egoistic exploitation of institutional weaknesses is partly due to
the people’s hurt feelings that are a result of the collective negative
experience of taking away traditional institutions which are part of the
traditional culture and thereby identity of the people. The exploitation of
institutional weaknesses and the misuse of institutions is further motivated
by the human pursuit of wealth and by the emotional longing for status so
typical of African societies and particularly common among traditional
chiefs (Wehrmann 2005)
6.2 Johannesburg, South Africa
The most previous institutional change in South Africa was the transition
from apartheid to the post-apartheid system. The change in law, giving –
among others – freedom of movement to everybody resulted in massive
migrations of Black people from homelands and townships towards the (big)
cities in search of work. In Johannesburg, many of these people looking for
housing became “victims” of the land mafia – or with other words had been
provided with land by the land mafia. The new-comers often stayed in shacks
they built in the backyard of friends or relatives living in a township
close to the city. Many of them became organized by local, informal
community leaders and often got into contact with the land mafia. A team of
land mafioso identified a group of landless, already organized people and
charge them R 50 (about US$ 10) each to sign up on a list. Once they had
brought together about 2000 signatures (which corresponds to R 100.000 / US$
20.000), they choosed a suitable site to occupy. This was planned very
precisely and often carried out with professional assistance. They completed
deeds searches on the land to determine who owns it and used skilled
planners to structure a settlement on paper. They avoided occupying private
land because they know that the government will treat them softer than
private owners. Once the squatters are settled, they had to pay a monthly R
50 (US$ 10) rent and an additional R 20 (US$ 4) „protection fee“ to the land
mafia. They also paid another R 10 (US$ 2,50) legal fee every month. The
legal fee was paid into a fund so that a legal representative could have
been called in if action would have been taken against the squatters (Reeves
1998; Wehrmann 1998).
Actors in this land conflict are the poor searching for land and the
people acting as land mafia. While the poor’s motivation is mainly the need
for shelter (material need), the land mafia is motivated by the search for
wealth (material and emotional need). The people acting as land mafia are
mainly state officials or well educated, highly qualified people who work
within the administration dealing with land issues or who have close
relations to state officials. They get the information from within the
system and exploit it for their private benefit – thereby exploiting the
state and taking advantage of institutional shortcomings – mainly concerning
the control of land development and the use of sanctions.
The example of the land mafia shows that land conflicts do also occur
even when a land registration/deeds cadastre is in place and when there are
just little or no institutional shortcomings. This underlines the importance
of psychic motivation, material and emotional needs as deeper causes of land
conflicts and highlights the need to address them if land conflicts shall be
limited.
6.3 Kenya
Misuse of power, motivated by psychic desires and the resulting emotional
and financial needs, are also the mayor cause of the big land conflicts in
Kenya which consist in land grabbing and illegal land allocations by
influential people. The Ndung’u report from 2004 revealed that the former
presidents Kenyatta and Moi as well as cabinet ministers, former high
ranking civil servants and other influential people illegally acquired title
deeds. They grabbed land from farmers as well as forest areas, game parks
and reserves – mainly with the support of public officials. The report asked
for the prosecution of those people who illegally gained land and those
public officials being involved in land grabbing. The report also demanded
to set up a Land Titles Tribunal to clarify ownership. As a final objective
all illegally acquired title deeds should be cancelled.
Fig. 5: Kenyatta and Moi accused of illegal land
allocation
Source: Daily Nation, 7.10.2004
This third example shows once more that the individual motivation of
people and their chances to manipulate the system are crucial factors in
land conflicts. The motivation can, however, be very different: a poor
landless person’s psychic desires and material needs resulting in the
illegal occupation of a small spot is definitely different from a
president’s psychic desires when he sells out state land or registers huge
areas on his own name. The crucial issue is to identify the emotional and
material needs and the psychic desires behind to find alternative solutions.
A person’s desire for power, influence and maybe even wealth might be
satisfied in a different way (e.g. by attributing additional status through
other means) which allows transferring at least part of the state and
private property back to the original owners.
7. CLASSIFICATION OF LAND CONFLICTS
Among the many different ways to classify land conflicts (Wehrmann 2005)
the one based on the social dimension of conflicts is the most suitable of
all – especially when it comes to conflict resolution. One possibility of
classification conflict research offers in this regard is the distinction
according to the social level where a conflict takes place: inner-personal,
interpersonal, inner-societal and inter-societal/international level. While
in the case of land conflicts the inner-personal level can be ignored, the
other three levels are very useful for a classification. Land conflicts
within one country will then occur at either the interpersonal or
inner-societal level (see Fig. 5).
Fig. 6: Classification of land conflicts according
to social level and dimension
Own draft
Another, however quite similar way of conflict classification is based on
the social dimension of the conflict, distinguishing between micro-societal,
meso-societal and macro-societal dimension. While the micro-societal
dimension is equivalent to the interpersonal level, the other two allow a
more precise classification of inner-societal conflicts (see Fig. 4).
The classification of land conflicts according to their social dimension
illustrates the high number and diversity of inner-societal land conflicts
compared to inter-personal land conflicts (which, however, does not tell
anything about their absolute number). While in most cases interpersonal
land conflicts can be addressed by existing formal or informal conflict
resolution bodies (see Wehrmann 2005), inner-societal conflicts are much
more difficult to tackle – mainly because conflict resolution mechanisms at
the higher level are part of the problem.
8. LAND CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND PREVENTION
In the long term, land conflicts can only be resolved and avoided if
addressed with an integral and system-oriented approach. Core elements of
conflict resolution and prevention are therefore the establishment of a
state under the rule of law and the implementation of good governance to
minimise the abuse of power and corruption. Beyond that, an active trauma
counselling and a reappraisal of historic injustice by integrating
psychotherapeutic methods are required to restore missing trust in the state
and its institutions. Further elements of conflict resolution are
functioning regulative and constitutive institutions of land markets, which
have been locally adapted, a transparent capital market and a coordinated
system of arbitration boards and jurisdiction. Good governance is of
particular importance in this context. Its criteria such as sustainability,
subsidiarity, equality, efficiency, transparency, accountability, public
participation and security – if applied to land tenure and urban land
management – form a good basis for development of cities in developing
countries to be relatively free of land conflicts (see WEHRMANN ET AL. 2002;
MAGEL/WEHRMANN 2001).
Tools and approaches to avoid and resettle land conflicts can be
distinguished in preventive and curative measures. The preventive measures
mainly focus on the institutional frame conditions such as:
- the establishment and strengthening of the constitutive institutions
(rule-of-law, secured land tenure and land registration/cadastre),
- the establishment and strengthening of the regulative institutions
(spatial planning, guided land use changes, land market monitoring, land
banking, proportional tax benefits for the state as land value increases
(mainly in peri-urban areas) and promotion of ethnic principles) and
- the establishment and control of an accessible and transparent capital
market.
The curative measures include a much broader range of activities.
Among them three types of measures can be distinguished:
- Conflict resolution, including moderation, mediation and arbitration.
Conflict resolution can take place at different levels; it can be applied
within the formal as well as within the informal sector or even in mixed
forms, so called hybrid structures. Conflict resettlement institutions can
also be based within the administration – be it the state or the
traditional administration.
- Land management, including different ways to clarify land rights and
secure tenure, surveying and land registration, land consolidation, land
readjustment, land sharing, land pooling, land use planning, investments
into the housing market (including housing for the middle class, social
housing, social concessions, site and service programs and site without
service programs), recovery of state assets and an increase of
transparency and documentation of land conflicts (e.g. through state land
inventories, special GIS which document land conflicts).
- Psychotherapeutical approaches. Land conflicts as any other type of
conflict often end up in vicious circles when the conflict parties stick
to their positions and unconsciously force each other to represent
increasingly extreme positions. People normally tend to project negative
characteristics on each other until the opposite party finally
incorporates them. Reality becomes more and more disguised and the other
conflict party ends up being responsible for all negative aspects in life,
e.g. squatters often make the state responsible for all their problems
while the state considers them as a handicap to any development. In such
situations it becomes necessary that both conflicting parties change their
perception of the other to pave for an equitable dialog. This can be
achieved by a sociodrama (a kind of psycho-analytical/therapeutical role
play). As generally it cannot be expected that both parties will do it
together, they can at least do it among themselves, thereby experiencing
the feelings of the other party and developing empathy for their position,
behaviour, interests and needs. As an alternative, street theatre and TV
soap operas can be used to deal with typical land conflicts people are
typically involved in.
Land conflicts can only be minimized if all approaches are combined as
required by the specific land conflict and adopted to the specific
situation, respecting existing rules, organisational structures and the
overall cultural, political, legal, economic and social frame conditions.
9. CONCLUSION
Institutional changes are conflict prone and therefore tend to be phases
of increased land conflicts. While some forms of land conflicts can occur
under different and even stabile institutional frame conditions (such as
border or inheritance conflicts), others depend on the kind of institutional
change. Multiple sales due to legal pluralism for instance are typical for
slow institutional changes that lead to the overlapping of two systems,
while illegal sales of state land are quite common in situations of either
abrupt institutional change that are marked by a temporary absence of rules
(transformation) or longer term absence of a functioning legitimated
institutional frame (civil war, dictatorship). The dimension of (the
physical and psychological) violence that occurs, however, always depends
strongly on the conflict asymmetry, which despite of all the differences of
land conflicts leads to similar patterns of inter-personal relations – a
fact that underlines the importance of the inherent psychosocial dynamic.
The case studies illustrate that institutional change as well as other
elements of change and a low level of development can result in massive
deficits in the institutional framework of land markets. These functional
weaknesses can enable land conflicts. Land conflicts are however rather
caused by the egoistic exploitation and intentional continuation of
institutional gaps and by the disregard of formal institutions than by an
absence of rules or an overlap of regulations. Reasons for this are of
psychical nature: The fact that the state widely ignores legitimate informal
institutions triggers off an act of defiance by the population. In turn,
governmental institutions and their rules are likewise disregarded. This can
lead to massive violations of land use regulations and consequently to land
use conflicts. The material desire for wealth and the emotional desire for
status – especially pronounced in African societies – additionally
contribute to the violation of regulations. In civil-war and post-conflict
countries, the exploitation and continuation of institutional weaknesses is
particularly common, which again can be understood when considering the
psychological factor. Civil war evokes and intensifies extreme psychical
fears (fear of loss and of existence) and desires (revenge, power), which
create particularly pronounced material needs for ensuring one’s livelihood
and wealth as well as emotional needs for respect and thus (moments of)
power. This means that almost all sections and social strata of the
population are involved in land conflicts, which are more diverse, more
frequent and more often result in violence than in a situation of legal
pluralism. Thus, the primary reasons for land conflicts are peoples’
psychical desires and fears as well as their emotional and material needs.
The pursuit of resulting individual interests is considerably facilitated by
the lack of an institutional framework. As a general rule, it can be assumed
that a weakness of those institutions constituting the land market enables
the outbreak of land ownership conflicts, while insufficient regulative
institutions result in land ownership and land use conflicts alike.
The complexity of causes leading to land conflicts as well as their
diversity and the huge number of different actors involved requires an
integral, system-oriented approach. Besides functioning constitutive and
regulative institutions and their adaptation to local requirements, a
transparent capital market and a coordinated system of arbitration boards
and legislation, the core elements of conflict resolution and prevention are
the establishment of rule-of-law principles, the implementation of good
governance to reduce abuses of authority and corruption as well as the
integration of psycho-therapeutical methods to re-establish mutual trust and
respect among conflict parties. In this context, good governance is of
particular importance. To transfer its criteria (sustainability,
subsidiarity, equality, efficiency, transparency, accountability, public
participation and security) on land policy and land management would provide
a good basis for sustainable and low-conflict development in African
countries. The due establishment of this positive framework is of crucial
importance, especially in situations of crisis such as in
post-conflict-countries. An established, legitimated and widely accepted
framework is necessary to avoid abuse and thus further land conflicts before
technical approaches like land registration can be implemented. Only then,
the following is true: „No matter how difficult concerted action might seem
in the chaos and confusion following conflict, land questions have to be
dealt with as early as possible” (Du Plessis 2003, p. 8). It goes without
saying that each land conflict needs its individual solutions which are
adapted to its local, regional, national and supranational political,
socioeconomic, cultural and power-related frame conditions. It depends on
each specific case which of the tools and approaches presented can or must
be applied for effective solutions on land conflicts.
REFERENCES
- Du Plessis, J. (2003): Land plays a key role in post-conflict
reconstruction. In: Habitat Debate, Vol. 9/4, p. 8.
- Magel, H. and Wehrmann, B. (2001): Applying Good Governance to Urban
Land Management – Why and How? In: Zeitschrift für Vermessungswesen (ZfV)
Vol. 126, pp. 310 – 316.
- Reeves, J. (1998): The move form slums to suburbs. In: Saturday Star,
21.2.1998.
- Wehrmann, B. (2005): Landkonflikte im urbanen und peri-urbanen Raum
von Großstädten in Entwicklungsländern – mit Beispielen aus Accra und
Phnom Penh. Urban and Peri-urban Land Conflicts in Developing Countries.
Berlin 2005.
- Wehrmann, B. (1998): Urban Informal Land Markets with a special focus
on South Africa. In: International Workshop on Comparative Policy
Perspectives on Urban Land Market Reform in Latin America, Southern Africa
and Eastern Europe. Workshop-documentation. Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA,
7 – 9.7.1998.
- Wehrmann, B. et al. (2002): Good Urban Land Management. In: Trialog
74, 3/2002, pp. 13 – 19.
BIOGRAPHICAL NOTES
The author is geographer and social anthropologist with many years work
experience in development cooperation and academic education. She has been
working in Europe, Africa, Asia and Latin America in the fields of urban and
rural development, governance and decentralisation as well as land
management and land policy. She did her PhD on land conflicts in developing
countries. From 1995 – 2000 she worked as junior expert for the German
Development Cooperation (GTZ). Since 2000 she is program manager at
Technische Universität München where she set up an international master’s
program on land management and land tenure. She is also conducting research
projects abroad and doing consultancy for different international
organisations. She has published more than a dozen articles on land and
development issues in developing countries.
CONTACTS
Dr. Babette Wehrmann
Technische Universität München, Centre of Land Management and Land Tenure
Arcisstr. 21
80290 Munich
GERMANY
Tel. + 49 – (0)89 - 28925789
Fax + 49 – (0)89 - 28923933
Email:
Wehrmann@landentwicklung-muenchen.de
Web site:
www.master-landmanagement.de
|